Standing between administrative monopoly and commercial monopoly Any behaviours that are to abuse administrative power to restrict or eliminate competition fall into the category of “administrative monopoly”. The subjects of the administrative monopoly include the following:
However, AML fails to exhaust the subjects that can abuse administrative powers to restrict or eliminate competition: Administrative Authorities’ indirect engagement into commercial activities by means of abusing their administrative powers and restricting free competition, normally in a way of their cooperation with particular enterprises, still flourishes in the economic activities, as one of the results from the long term tradition of integration of governments with enterprises and special protection to state-owned enterprises. To investigate the abovementioned violations faces an embarrassing situation that how the laws should apply — on the one hand, neither the Administrative Authorities conduct any direct monopolistic activities nor the particular enterprises have any administrative powers, which removes the grounds of application of Chapter 5 (Administrative Monopoly) of AML; on the other hand, Chapter 2 (Monopoly Agreement) of AML cannot apply either, because Administrative Authorities and the particular enterprises in the cooperation are not those undertakings who are competitive or have upstream and downstream relationship; moreover, even if we investigate such particular enterprises only, the investigation will probably demonstrate that they normally are not dominant in the market but are able to acquire and maintain monopolies with the aid of administrative powers, so Chapter 3 (Abuse of Dominant Market Position) of AML cannot apply. The behaviours that impair competition as described above are closely connected with the abuse of administrative powers and cannot be effectively prohibited by current provisions of AML. Therefore, we define them as “hidden monopoly”. Scarce resources Such collusion between the Administrative Authorities and enterprises also exists widely in the areas of governmental procurement, Industry regulation Suggestions
行政合规中的”隐性垄断”问题
但是,《反垄断法》对滥用行政权力排除、限制竞争的主体的规定并不完善:由於中国政企不分、偏袒国企的传统,经济活动中存在大量行政机关滥用行政权力间接参与商业活动、妨害自由竞争的情形,这些妨害竞争的行为通常以政府与特定企业合作的方式进行。查处上述违法行为时法律适用上可能存在难点–从表面看,行政机关没有直接实施垄断活动,相关企业又没有行政权力,均无法适用《反垄断法》第五章(行政垄断)的规定;而行政机关与相关企业的合作又并非具有竞争关系或者上下游关系的经营者,无法适用《反垄断法》第二章(垄断协议)的规定;如果针对相关企业的行为单独进行查处,此类企业又往往不具备市场支配地位,而是凭借行政权力的支持才能维持垄断,自然也无法适用《反垄断法》第三章(滥用市场支配地位)的规定。 这一类妨害竞争的行为与行政权力的滥用存在密切关系,但又不能被《反垄断法》的现有规定所有效禁止,我们将其称为”隐性垄断”。 稀缺资源分配中的隐性垄断 此类政企通谋的情形亦常见於政府采购、招标投标等领域。政府采购订单、建设项目、承办会议等商业机会通常金额巨大,广义上可以视作”稀缺资源”;而且随着查处力度的增强,行为模式有越来越隐蔽的趋势。因此,这类行为同样可归类为稀缺资源分配中的隐性垄断。 行业监管中的隐性垄断 根据我们的调查研究,此类隐性垄断发生的典型领域包括(1)出租车牌照管理:地方政府严格控制出租车牌照发放,导致出租车准入门槛过高,难以形成有效竞争,进而催生潜在的地方政府和出租车公司”共谋”垄断风险;(2)驾校申办许可:实践中各地道路运输管理部门以行业监管为由,为驾校申办设置层层隐性门槛,从而导致市场中驾校供给短缺,消费者不得不接受既有驾校质次价高的服务;(3)汽车品牌销售:自2005年《汽车品牌销售管理实施办法》生效后,汽车品牌销售一直是品牌独家授权制。汽车生产企业(即整车企业)凭借品牌优势,完全控制了汽车销售的上下游市场。汽车品牌销售的纵向垄断是表象,其实质问题是行业监管中出现的隐性垄断。 建议
________________ 8F, Kerry Parkside Office,1155 Fang Dian Road, Shanghai 201204, P. R. China |
China (PRC)
Latest Updates
Related Articles
Related Articles by Jurisdiction
Windows of opportunity
Fengming Liu, Chief Legal Officer of Microsoft’s Greater China Region, shares the challenges facing his in-house team and reveals how the software giant will use the downturn to hire and develop legal talent.
Latest Articles